Articles by alphabetic order
A B C D E F G H I J K L M N O P Q R S T U V W X Y Z
 Ā Ī Ñ Ś Ū Ö Ō
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0


Difference between revisions of "Power and Inequality in Buddhism"

From Tibetan Buddhist Encyclopedia
Jump to navigation Jump to search
(Created page with "{{DisplayImages|3270|856|2058|448|886|2561|1002|3392|452|1786|100|4446|880|2764|4182}} {{Centre|<big><big>Power and Inequality in Buddhism </big></big><br/> By Indrajala (Je...")
 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{DisplayImages|3270|856|2058|448|886|2561|1002|3392|452|1786|100|4446|880|2764|4182}}
+
{{DisplayImages|3270|856|2058|448|886|2561|1002|3392|452|1786|100|4446}}
 
{{Centre|<big><big>Power and Inequality in Buddhism </big></big><br/>
 
{{Centre|<big><big>Power and Inequality in Buddhism </big></big><br/>
 
By [[Indrajala (Jeffrey Kotyk)]]}}<br/><br/>
 
By [[Indrajala (Jeffrey Kotyk)]]}}<br/><br/>
  
The nature of power and authority within Buddhism is a potentially volatile subject, especially for many modern day people who advocate equality and egalitarianism. Such ideals are no doubt heavily influenced by modern movements towards democracy and such recent ideologies as feminism which seeks to correct perceived inequalities and injustices. Buddhism in popular culture is normally perceived as being egalitarian and quite compatible with liberal western democratic values. Not only is it a religion of tolerance, but one that promotes equality.
+
The [[nature]] of power and authority within [[Buddhism]] is a potentially volatile [[subject]], especially for many {{Wiki|modern}} day [[people]] who advocate equality and egalitarianism. Such ideals are no [[doubt]] heavily influenced by {{Wiki|modern}} movements towards {{Wiki|democracy}} and such recent ideologies as {{Wiki|feminism}} which seeks to correct [[perceived]] inequalities and injustices. [[Buddhism]] in popular {{Wiki|culture}} is normally [[perceived]] as being {{Wiki|egalitarian}} and quite compatible with liberal {{Wiki|western}} democratic values. Not only is it a [[religion]] of [[tolerance]], but one that promotes equality.
  
Such prescriptive ideals are at odds with the historical and present realities. Historically long ago hierarchy and inequality became essentially hard wired into the institutional religion(s) we call Buddhism(s), and we will look at this in this post. This might be disagreeable to contemporary western sensibilities, but until recently, and perhaps even still, a prescribed hierarchy and vast degree of inequality between Buddhists would not have registered as problematic for most Asian cultures.
+
Such prescriptive ideals are at odds with the historical and {{Wiki|present}} [[realities]]. Historically long ago {{Wiki|hierarchy}} and inequality became [[essentially]] hard wired into the institutional religion(s) we call Buddhism(s), and we will look at this in this post. This might be [[disagreeable]] to contemporary {{Wiki|western}} sensibilities, but until recently, and perhaps even still, a prescribed {{Wiki|hierarchy}} and vast [[degree]] of inequality between [[Buddhists]] would not have registered as problematic for most {{Wiki|Asian}} cultures.
  
The Buddha is on record as having told his disciples two pertinent things in respect to how the tradition he founded was to be developed and practised. It needs firstly to be noted that he never appointed a successor, though figures like Mahākāśyapa did take a lead role in formulating the canon according to the traditional histories. He also insisted that practitioners be “islands onto themselves”. This is significant because it illustrates that a strict hierarchy based on spiritual authority and autocratic control of a community was not the Buddha's intent. As the founder of the sangha he had a degree of charismatic authority no doubt, but he did in fact establish a democratic mechanism within the sangha for deciding on matters through tacit consent of the whole assembly.
+
The [[Buddha]] is on record as having told his [[disciples]] two pertinent things in [[respect]] to how the [[tradition]] he founded was to be developed and practised. It needs firstly to be noted that he never appointed a successor, though figures like [[Mahākāśyapa]] did take a lead role in formulating the [[canon]] according to the [[traditional]] histories. He also insisted that practitioners be “islands onto themselves”. This is significant because it illustrates that a strict {{Wiki|hierarchy}} based on [[spiritual]] authority and autocratic control of a {{Wiki|community}} was not the [[Buddha's]] intent. As the founder of the [[sangha]] he had a [[degree]] of {{Wiki|charismatic}} authority no [[doubt]], but he did in fact establish a democratic {{Wiki|mechanism}} within the [[sangha]] for deciding on matters through tacit consent of the whole assembly.
  
 
Let us consider two relevant quotes as follows.
 
Let us consider two relevant quotes as follows.
  
: Therefore, Ananda, be islands unto yourselves, refuges unto yourselves, seeking no external refuge; with the Dhamma as your island, the Dhamma as your refuge, seeking no other refuge. (DN 16)
+
: Therefore, [[Ananda]], be islands unto yourselves, [[refuges]] unto yourselves, seeking no external [[refuge]]; with the [[Dhamma]] as your island, the [[Dhamma]] as your [[refuge]], seeking no other [[refuge]]. (DN 16)
  
Here is the famous statement where the Buddha instructs us to rely on ourselves with the Dharma/Dhamma as our refuge. He does not instruct Ānanda to rely on lineage or authority. We also have the Buddha explicitly stating he will appoint no successor.
+
Here is the famous statement where the [[Buddha]] instructs us to rely on ourselves with the Dharma/Dhamma as our [[refuge]]. He does not instruct [[Ānanda]] to rely on [[lineage]] or authority. We also have the [[Buddha]] explicitly stating he will appoint no successor.
  
: “Is there, Master Ananda, any single bhikkhu who was appointed by Master Gotama thus: ‘He will be your refuge when I am gone,’ and whom you now have recourse to?”
+
: “Is there, [[Master]] [[Ananda]], any single [[bhikkhu]] who was appointed by [[Master Gotama]] thus: ‘He will be your [[refuge]] when I am gone,’ and whom you now have recourse to?”
  
: “There is no single bhikkhu, brahmin, who was appointed by the Blessed One who knows and sees, accomplished and fully enlightened, thus: ‘He will be your refuge when I am gone,’ and whom we now have recourse to.”
+
: “There is no single [[bhikkhu]], [[brahmin]], who was appointed by the [[Blessed One]] who [[knows]] and sees, accomplished and fully [[enlightened]], thus: ‘He will be your [[refuge]] when I am gone,’ and whom we now have recourse to.”
  
: “But is there, Master Ananda, any single bhikkhu who has been chosen by the Sangha and appointed by a number of elder bhikkhus thus: ‘He will be our refuge after the Blessed One has gone,’ and whom you now have recourse to?”
+
: “But is there, [[Master]] [[Ananda]], any single [[bhikkhu]] who has been chosen by the [[Sangha]] and appointed by a number of elder [[bhikkhus]] thus: ‘He will be our [[refuge]] after the [[Blessed One]] has gone,’ and whom you now have recourse to?”
  
: “There is no single bhikkhu, brahmin, who has been chosen by the Sangha and appointed by a number of elder bhikkhus thus: ‘He will be our refuge after the Blessed One has gone,’ and whom we now have recourse to.”
+
: “There is no single [[bhikkhu]], [[brahmin]], who has been chosen by the [[Sangha]] and appointed by a number of elder [[bhikkhus]] thus: ‘He will be our [[refuge]] after the [[Blessed One]] has gone,’ and whom we now have recourse to.”
  
: “But if you have no refuge, Master Ananda, what is the cause for your concord?”
+
: “But if you have no [[refuge]], [[Master]] [[Ananda]], what is the [[cause]] for your [[concord]]?”
  
: “We are not without a refuge, brahmin. We have a refuge; we have the Dhamma as our refuge.”
+
: “We are not without a [[refuge]], [[brahmin]]. We have a [[refuge]]; we have the [[Dhamma]] as our [[refuge]].”
::(MN 108)
+
::(MN [[108]])
  
According to this, the Buddha placed spiritual authority in the Dharma rather than a human successor or even the assembly of arhats which might have been a logical option. There is no mention of lineage blessings or some type of “Dharma transmission” which would bestow institutional authority on select individuals. It seems that, based on the early canon, there is no basis for lineages as they came to develop. Spiritual authority was first placed in the abstract Dharma. This would mean no person could claim special status or privileges based on title or appointment. A person was to be judged based on their cultivation of Dharma.
+
According to this, the [[Buddha]] placed [[spiritual]] authority in the [[Dharma]] rather than a [[human]] successor or even the assembly of [[arhats]] which might have been a [[logical]] option. There is no mention of [[lineage]] [[blessings]] or some type of “[[Dharma transmission]]” which would bestow institutional authority on select {{Wiki|individuals}}. It seems that, based on the early [[canon]], there is no basis for [[lineages]] as they came to develop. [[Spiritual]] authority was first placed in the abstract [[Dharma]]. This would mean no [[person]] could claim special {{Wiki|status}} or privileges based on title or appointment. A [[person]] was to be judged based on their [[cultivation]] of [[Dharma]].
  
Nevertheless, as a community there were still means to adjudicate and make collective decisions. While the dating of the Vinaya literature is debated, I believe that at least some of it reflects historical fact or at least a somewhat later cultural memory of how things were established originally.
+
Nevertheless, as a {{Wiki|community}} there were still means to adjudicate and make collective decisions. While the dating of the [[Vinaya]] {{Wiki|literature}} is [[debated]], I believe that at least some of it reflects historical fact or at least a somewhat later {{Wiki|cultural}} [[memory]] of how things were established originally.
  
One example of this are the more or less democratic procedures with which formal decisions were made within the sangha such as ordinations, forced exiles and other such matters. The karma proceedings as they are called are carried out through tacit consent. Basically, a proposition would be put forward before the required minimum number of present bhikṣus and provided there were no objections and the assembly remained silent it would be passed. If any objections arose, then they had to be resolved before the motion was passed.
+
One example of this are the more or less democratic procedures with which formal decisions were made within the [[sangha]] such as ordinations, forced exiles and other such matters. The [[karma]] proceedings as they are called are carried out through tacit consent. Basically, a proposition would be put forward before the required minimum number of {{Wiki|present}} [[bhikṣus]] and provided there were no objections and the assembly remained [[silent]] it would be passed. If any objections arose, then they had to be resolved before the {{Wiki|motion}} was passed.
  
In light of all this, we might ask what basis there is for appointed titles and leadership roles that effectively function as autocracies, especially outside of India?
+
In {{Wiki|light}} of all this, we might ask what basis there is for appointed titles and [[leadership]] roles that effectively [[function]] as autocracies, especially outside of [[India]]?
  
We need to consider the fact that as Buddhism spread to foreign lands, such as China, the original democratic principles enshrined in the Vinaya would have seemed quite alien to heavily hierarchical societies which determined authority based on one's ancestry. This naturally led to a reproduction of clan-like structures in the Buddhist communities where monastic disciples functioned as adopted sons.
+
We need to consider the fact that as [[Buddhism]] spread to foreign lands, such as [[China]], the original democratic {{Wiki|principles}} enshrined in the [[Vinaya]] would have seemed quite alien to heavily hierarchical {{Wiki|societies}} which determined authority based on one's ancestry. This naturally led to a reproduction of clan-like structures in the [[Buddhist]] communities where [[monastic]] [[disciples]] functioned as adopted sons.
  
In Chinese Buddhism from early on it seems that legitimacy was decided based on constructed lineage charts with sufficient aggrandized figures throughout the past, which was not at all unlike family tablets and the mechanism for legitimizing elite power. Having no formal leadership and deciding on things by vote would not have worked in such a culture. This perhaps also helps to explain why the karma proceedings as per the Vinaya were never really implemented throughout Chinese history despite the texts for it having been translated in the early fifth century.
+
In [[Chinese Buddhism]] from early on it seems that legitimacy was decided based on [[constructed]] [[lineage]] charts with sufficient aggrandized figures throughout the {{Wiki|past}}, which was not at all unlike family tablets and the {{Wiki|mechanism}} for legitimizing {{Wiki|elite}} power. Having no formal [[leadership]] and deciding on things by vote would not have worked in such a {{Wiki|culture}}. This perhaps also helps to explain why the [[karma]] proceedings as per the [[Vinaya]] were never really implemented throughout {{Wiki|Chinese}} history despite the texts for it having been translated in the early fifth century.
  
However, the formation of hierarchy and lineage in Buddhism is rooted in other factors. The analysis here can go a lot deeper with recourse to general sociology. Human organizations tend towards individuals forming cliques and acquiring collective power for themselves. In a religious context spiritual authority is often just as potent as economic, social and cultural powers. Spiritual capital is also exchangeable for economic and political capitals as well, which furthers the aims of a given institution within a society. A religious institution will inevitably want state sanction plus a stable economic base with which to develop and expand its infrastructure and membership. This is in contrast to unorganized religious communities where power is dispersed and consequently complex projects, such as defensive strategies against hostile forces as the Buddhists required, prove difficult if not simply infeasible.
+
However, the formation of {{Wiki|hierarchy}} and [[lineage]] in [[Buddhism]] is rooted in other factors. The analysis here can go a lot deeper with recourse to general {{Wiki|sociology}}. [[Human]] organizations tend towards {{Wiki|individuals}} forming cliques and acquiring collective power for themselves. In a [[religious]] context [[spiritual]] authority is often just as potent as economic, {{Wiki|social}} and {{Wiki|cultural}} [[powers]]. [[Spiritual]] capital is also exchangeable for economic and {{Wiki|political}} capitals as well, which furthers the aims of a given institution within a {{Wiki|society}}. A [[religious]] institution will inevitably want state sanction plus a {{Wiki|stable}} economic base with which to develop and expand its infrastructure and membership. This is in contrast to unorganized [[religious]] communities where power is dispersed and consequently complex projects, such as defensive strategies against {{Wiki|hostile}} forces as the [[Buddhists]] required, prove difficult if not simply infeasible.
  
I should say something about Pierre Bourdieu's (1930-2002) model here. It is actually quite useful when analysing power structures within Buddhism. In his work The Forms of Capital (1986), he specifies three types of capital:
+
I should say something about Pierre Bourdieu's (1930-2002) model here. It is actually quite useful when analysing power structures within [[Buddhism]]. In his work The [[Forms]] of Capital (1986), he specifies three types of capital:
  
 
*Economic capital: economic resources such as cash and assets.
 
*Economic capital: economic resources such as cash and assets.
* Social capital: resources linked to a “durable network of more or less institutionalized relationships of mutual acquaintance and recognition”.
+
* {{Wiki|Social}} capital: resources linked to a “[[durable]] network of more or less institutionalized relationships of mutual acquaintance and [[recognition]]”.
* Cultural capital: knowledge, education and skills which elevates someone to a higher status in their society.
+
* {{Wiki|Cultural}} capital: [[knowledge]], [[education]] and skills which elevates someone to a higher {{Wiki|status}} in their {{Wiki|society}}.
  
Bourdieu's theory was quite innovative in that he addressed the issue of inequality by looking at factors outside the immediate economic sphere. This is especially pertinent to Buddhism where inequality historically has and still exists. John Field explains Boudieu's concern with social hierarchy:
+
Bourdieu's {{Wiki|theory}} was quite innovative in that he addressed the issue of inequality by looking at factors outside the immediate economic [[sphere]]. This is especially pertinent to [[Buddhism]] where inequality historically has and still [[exists]]. John Field explains Boudieu's [[concern]] with {{Wiki|social}} {{Wiki|hierarchy}}:
  
: To understand Bourdieu's thinking on social capital, we need to remember that his main concern was and is the understanding of social hierarchy. In many ways, he was engaging with a body of ideas that was deeply influenced by Marxist sociology. He thought that 'economic capital is at the root of all other types of capital', and he was interested in the ways in which it could be combined with other forms of capital to create and reproduce inequality. For Bourdieu, inequality was to be explained by the production and reproduction of capital. He reminded that readers that captial 'is accumulated labor' which 'takes time to accumulate'. But to see capital solely in economic terms was insufficient. Certainly economic exchanges are geared towards profit, and are therefore pursued out of self-interest. Yet Bourdieu challenged the conventional view that immaterial exchanges - the universe of the artist, or that of love and marriage - were somehow to be respected as 'disinterested'. Both cultural capital and social capital should be treated as assets, representing the product of accumulated labour.<ref>{{Nolinking|John Field, Social Capital, Second Edition (Routledge, 2009), 18.}}</ref>
+
: To understand Bourdieu's [[thinking]] on {{Wiki|social}} capital, we need to remember that his main [[concern]] was and is the [[understanding]] of {{Wiki|social}} {{Wiki|hierarchy}}. In many ways, he was engaging with a [[body]] of [[ideas]] that was deeply influenced by {{Wiki|Marxist}} {{Wiki|sociology}}. He [[thought]] that 'economic capital is at the [[root]] of all other types of capital', and he was [[interested]] in the ways in which it could be combined with other [[forms]] of capital to create and reproduce inequality. For Bourdieu, inequality was to be explained by the production and reproduction of capital. He reminded that readers that captial 'is [[accumulated]] labor' which 'takes [[time]] to [[accumulate]]'. But to see capital solely in economic terms was insufficient. Certainly economic exchanges are geared towards profit, and are therefore pursued out of self-interest. Yet Bourdieu challenged the [[Wikipedia:Convention (norm)|conventional]] [[view]] that {{Wiki|immaterial}} exchanges - the [[universe]] of the artist, or that of [[love]] and [[marriage]] - were somehow to be respected as 'disinterested'. Both {{Wiki|cultural}} capital and {{Wiki|social}} capital should be treated as assets, representing the product of [[accumulated]] labour.<ref>{{Nolinking|John Field, Social Capital, Second Edition (Routledge, 2009), 18.}}</ref>
  
I believe we can also add spiritual capital to the above list as a unique form of capital which promotes interests beyond economic means. It would of course be related to cultural and social capitals, but beyond that there is a sort of power that comes with widespread belief in some religious icon, person or idea that is convertible into other forms of capital and which fosters inequality within a given community.
+
I believe we can also add [[spiritual]] capital to the above list as a unique [[form]] of capital which promotes interests beyond economic means. It would of course be related to {{Wiki|cultural}} and {{Wiki|social}} capitals, but beyond that there is a sort of power that comes with widespread [[belief]] in some [[religious]] icon, [[person]] or [[idea]] that is convertible into other [[forms]] of capital and which fosters inequality within a given {{Wiki|community}}.
  
In Buddhism these four types of capital are all present.
+
In [[Buddhism]] these four types of capital are all {{Wiki|present}}.
  
Spiritual capital would be the ability to command the labor and resources of a community based on people's religious beliefs. The lowly laywoman in the temple kitchen has no spiritual capital and thus would receive no offerings from the larger community. She would exercise minimal power in the decision making process. In traditional Buddhist thought her gender would be seen as a handicap to spiritual attainments and her lack of renunciate status would likewise diminish her chances of acquiring any spiritual capital. Meanwhile the celebrated renunciate arhat would possess vast stores of spiritual capital despite not having a dime to his (or her) name. This spiritual capital would be just as valuable as social or cultural capital as the faith in him as a "field of merit" and teacher of liberation could literally move mountains if he asked for a monastery to be built and sufficient numbers of people believed in him.
+
[[Spiritual]] capital would be the ability to command the labor and resources of a {{Wiki|community}} based on people's [[religious]] [[beliefs]]. The lowly [[laywoman]] in the [[temple]] kitchen has no [[spiritual]] capital and thus would receive no [[offerings]] from the larger {{Wiki|community}}. She would exercise minimal power in the {{Wiki|decision making}} process. In [[traditional]] [[Buddhist]] [[thought]] her [[gender]] would be seen as a handicap to [[spiritual]] [[attainments]] and her lack of renunciate {{Wiki|status}} would likewise {{Wiki|diminish}} her chances of acquiring any [[spiritual]] capital. Meanwhile the celebrated renunciate [[arhat]] would possess vast stores of [[spiritual]] capital despite not having a dime to his (or her) [[name]]. This [[spiritual]] capital would be just as valuable as {{Wiki|social}} or {{Wiki|cultural}} capital as the [[faith]] in him as a "[[field of merit]]" and [[teacher]] of [[liberation]] could literally move [[mountains]] if he asked for a [[monastery]] to be built and sufficient numbers of [[people]] believed in him.
  
Cultural capital would be all the skills and knowledge necessary for priestcraft, religious theater, exegesis, chanting, scripture copying and related fields. One prime example of cultural capital in much of the Buddhist world is skill in calligraphy. Tibetan and East Asian monks can spend many years perfecting their art. Kūkai's work so admired that people to this day emulate his hand; both his Chinese characters and siddham script (Sanskrit). In premodern East Asia skill at calligraphy was a sign of good education, personal cultivation, patience and class, all of which distinguished the master from the common monastics. In modern days as well the fine works of eminent figures are prominently displayed for the public to admire and even emulate. Around many contemporary Taiwanese monasteries the works of their respective masters are positioned in key locations for people to readily view, such as in the dining or reception halls. The work of anyone else is only naturally not considered worthy enough. The master's work raised above all not only affirms his or her status, but indirectly diminishes the status of everyone else. As representatives of their organization their calligraphy can essentially function as subtle power projection where a sharp eye can admire their skill which would only naturally reflect their other good qualities such as leadership.
+
{{Wiki|Cultural}} capital would be all the skills and [[knowledge]] necessary for priestcraft, [[religious]] theater, {{Wiki|exegesis}}, [[chanting]], [[scripture]] copying and related fields. One prime example of {{Wiki|cultural}} capital in much of the [[Buddhist]] [[world]] is skill in {{Wiki|calligraphy}}. [[Tibetan]] and {{Wiki|East Asian}} [[monks]] can spend many years perfecting their [[art]]. [[Kūkai's]] work so admired that [[people]] to this day emulate his hand; both his {{Wiki|Chinese}} characters and [[siddham]] script ([[Sanskrit]]). In premodern {{Wiki|East Asia}} skill at {{Wiki|calligraphy}} was a sign of good [[education]], personal [[cultivation]], [[patience]] and class, all of which {{Wiki|distinguished}} the [[master]] from the common [[monastics]]. In {{Wiki|modern}} days as well the fine works of {{Wiki|eminent}} figures are prominently displayed for the public to admire and even emulate. Around many contemporary [[Wikipedia:Taiwanese people|Taiwanese]] [[monasteries]] the works of their respective [[masters]] are positioned in key locations for [[people]] to readily [[view]], such as in the dining or {{Wiki|reception}} halls. The work of anyone else is only naturally not considered [[worthy]] enough. The [[master's]] work raised above all not only affirms his or her {{Wiki|status}}, but indirectly {{Wiki|diminishes}} the {{Wiki|status}} of everyone else. As representatives of their organization their {{Wiki|calligraphy}} can [[essentially]] [[function]] as {{Wiki|subtle}} power projection where a sharp [[eye]] can admire their skill which would only naturally reflect their other good qualities such as [[leadership]].
  
Social capital within Buddhism might be best illustrated by lineages or sects. Membership in a given lineage brings with it various privileges which might include immediate access to material resources, even simple things like free food and shelter which outsiders would be forced to pay for with labor or cash. The status that comes with having an elevated position within an organization further amplifies inequality. For instance, if you are a senior monk you probably will not be asked to sweep the floor and clean toilets, whereas the lowly novices are given such dirty jobs and in due time they pass such tasks on to their underlings. Those in elevated social positions within a Buddhist organization generally enjoy the fruits of others' labours, and all this is justifiable given their social status.
+
{{Wiki|Social}} capital within [[Buddhism]] might be best [[illustrated]] by [[lineages]] or sects. Membership in a given [[lineage]] brings with it various privileges which might include immediate access to material resources, even simple things like free [[food]] and [[shelter]] which outsiders would be forced to pay for with labor or cash. The {{Wiki|status}} that comes with having an elevated position within an organization further amplifies inequality. For instance, if you are a senior [[monk]] you probably will not be asked to sweep the floor and clean [[toilets]], whereas the lowly novices are given such dirty jobs and in due [[time]] they pass such tasks on to their underlings. Those in elevated {{Wiki|social}} positions within a [[Buddhist]] organization generally enjoy the {{Wiki|fruits}} of others' labours, and all this is justifiable given their {{Wiki|social status}}.
  
The official sangha is tied in with social capital as well. The sangha is a “field of merit”. This is a social construct where formally ordained monastics are given material offerings as a means of generating merit which is believed to result in good tidings in this and future lives. Their position is strictly demarcated from that of common laypeople. The laypeople cook the rice and give it to the monks and receive merit plus teachings. The sangha might request the laypeople construct something on their behalf (the classic example is a meditation hut) and given the accumulated capital of the sangha it probably gets done. Here we see the interplay between the different forms of capital. Cultural, social and spiritual capitals are easily converted to physical goods and services, as well as economic capital.
+
The official [[sangha]] is tied in with {{Wiki|social}} capital as well. The [[sangha]] is a “[[field of merit]]”. This is a {{Wiki|social}} construct where formally [[ordained]] [[monastics]] are given material [[offerings]] as a means of generating [[merit]] which is believed to result in good tidings in this and {{Wiki|future}} [[lives]]. Their position is strictly demarcated from that of common laypeople. The laypeople cook the {{Wiki|rice}} and give it to the [[monks]] and receive [[merit]] plus teachings. The [[sangha]] might request the laypeople construct something on their behalf (the classic example is a [[meditation]] hut) and given the [[accumulated]] capital of the [[sangha]] it probably gets done. Here we see the interplay between the different [[forms]] of capital. {{Wiki|Cultural}}, {{Wiki|social}} and [[spiritual]] capitals are easily converted to [[physical]] goods and services, as well as economic capital.
  
For many centuries the sangha has found itself in a kind of dual world where on one hand as renunciates having personal wealth was ostensibly taboo and contrary to the Vinaya, and on the other would accumulate vast amounts of assets and cash as a collective body. People and states would make offerings of land and money to the sangha in exchange for merit, teachings, social unification and regime legitimization (see my earlier post entitled [[Buddhism & Early States - Tibet and Japan]] ). In many cases throughout Buddhist history economic capital was essential in acquiring the other forms of capital. In order to become literate and able to compose decent verses in East Asia for example one needed paper, a set of the classics, a tutor and other such essentials, all of which cost money. A monastery could in theory provide such things, but again this possibly came with a financial cost in China which had a cash economy.  
+
For many centuries the [[sangha]] has found itself in a kind of dual [[world]] where on one hand as renunciates having personal [[wealth]] was ostensibly {{Wiki|taboo}} and contrary to the [[Vinaya]], and on the other would [[accumulate]] vast amounts of assets and cash as a collective [[body]]. [[People]] and states would make [[offerings]] of land and [[money]] to the [[sangha]] in exchange for [[merit]], teachings, {{Wiki|social}} unification and regime legitimization (see my earlier post entitled [[Buddhism & Early States - Tibet and Japan]] ). In many cases throughout [[Buddhist]] history economic capital was [[essential]] in acquiring the other [[forms]] of capital. In order to become literate and able to compose decent verses in {{Wiki|East Asia}} for example one needed paper, a set of the classics, a tutor and other such [[essentials]], all of which cost [[money]]. A [[monastery]] could in {{Wiki|theory}} provide such things, but again this possibly came with a financial cost in [[China]] which had a cash {{Wiki|economy}}.  
  
Even spiritual capital in some cases had to be acquired through exchanging economic capital. One prime example of this is the necessity to make expensive offerings in order to receive some tantric empowerments, though having such empowerments in some cultures elevated one's social status and ability to acquire further capital. Kūkai for instance was able to have several large monasteries built after returning from China because he could offer the aristocracy new and advanced forms of ritual technology from the continent which they saw great benefit in. He alone did not have sufficient economic capital to build such institutions, but his spiritual capital, which was gained through a trip to China paid for with gold, was eventually convertible to real life goods and services well beyond his economic means to acquire.
+
Even [[spiritual]] capital in some cases had to be acquired through exchanging economic capital. One prime example of this is the necessity to make expensive [[offerings]] in order to receive some [[tantric]] [[empowerments]], though having such [[empowerments]] in some cultures elevated one's {{Wiki|social status}} and ability to acquire further capital. [[Kūkai]] for instance was able to have several large [[monasteries]] built after returning from [[China]] because he could offer the {{Wiki|aristocracy}} new and advanced [[forms]] of [[ritual]] technology from the continent which they saw great [[benefit]] in. He alone did not have sufficient economic capital to build such {{Wiki|institutions}}, but his [[spiritual]] capital, which was gained through a trip to [[China]] paid for with {{Wiki|gold}}, was eventually convertible to real [[life]] goods and services well beyond his economic means to acquire.
  
It is of course quite reasonable in some contexts to consciously attempt to gain a monopoly over spiritual authority because a dispersion of that authority would not only undermine the personal power base of religious elites needed for a linear direction, but also undermine the accumulated spiritual authority necessary for substantial projects which further the interests of both the common devotee and the ecclesiastical elites.
+
It is of course quite reasonable in some contexts to [[consciously]] attempt to gain a monopoly over [[spiritual]] authority because a dispersion of that authority would not only undermine the personal power base of [[religious]] elites needed for a linear [[direction]], but also undermine the [[accumulated]] [[spiritual]] authority necessary for substantial projects which further the interests of both the common [[devotee]] and the {{Wiki|ecclesiastical}} elites.
  
We can identify one early example of such an attempt at power acquisition in early Buddhist literature. For instance, according to the Milindapanha (the Questions of Milinda), in order to attain arhatship and live through it one must formally ordain as a bhikṣu/bhikkhu, otherwise as a layperson one will die within a day. Consider the following:
+
We can identify one early example of such an attempt at power acquisition in early [[Buddhist literature]]. For instance, according to the [[Milindapanha]] (the [[Questions of Milinda]]), in order to attain [[arhatship]] and live through it one must formally ordain as a bhikṣu/bhikkhu, otherwise as a [[layperson]] one will [[die]] within a day. Consider the following:
  
: "If a layman attains arahant-ship, only two destinations await him; either he must enter the Order that very day or else he must attain parinibbàna"
+
: "If a [[layman]] attains [[arahant-ship]], only two destinations await him; either he must enter the Order that very day or else he must attain parinibbàna"
  
:: Milindapanha III.19
+
:: [[Milindapanha]] III.19
  
: "You say that if a layman attains arahantship he must either enter the Order that very day or die and attain parinibbàna. Yet if he is unable to find a robe and bowl and preceptor then that exalted condition of arahantship is a waste, for destruction of life is involved in it."
+
: "You say that if a [[layman]] attains [[arahantship]] he must either enter the Order that very day or [[die]] and attain parinibbàna. Yet if he is unable to find a robe and [[bowl]] and [[preceptor]] then that [[exalted]] [[condition]] of [[arahantship]] is a waste, for destruction of [[life]] is involved in it."
  
: "The fault does not lie with arahantship but with the state of a layman, because it is too weak to support arahantship. Just as, O king, although food protects the life of beings it will take away the life of one whose digestion is weak; so too, if a layman attains arahantship he must, because of the weakness of that condition, enter the Order that very day or die."
+
: "The fault does not lie with [[arahantship]] but with the state of a [[layman]], because it is too weak to support [[arahantship]]. Just as, O [[king]], although [[food]] protects the [[life]] of [[beings]] it will take away the [[life]] of one whose {{Wiki|digestion}} is weak; so too, if a [[layman]] attains [[arahantship]] he must, because of the weakness of that [[condition]], enter the Order that very day or [[die]]."
  
:: Milindapanha III.62
+
:: [[Milindapanha]] III.62
  
We need to consider what this is really saying and who benefits from such a belief. As Cicero suggested: cui bono? Who benefits from this? Unless we accept the stated belief as is, we might wonder if there is not an alternative motive behind these ideas.
+
We need to consider what this is really saying and who benefits from such a [[belief]]. As {{Wiki|Cicero}} suggested: cui bono? Who benefits from this? Unless we accept the stated [[belief]] as is, we might wonder if there is not an alternative {{Wiki|motive}} behind these [[ideas]].
  
It is essentially saying that the formally ordained monastic sangha has a monopoly on living arhats. Why would this be important? To answer this we might look at a certain early Buddhist text in Chinese, perhaps translated in the third or fourth century which, like the Dhammapada, contains short quotes from various sūtras. It is called the Sūtra in Forty-Two Sections. The following line is relevant to what we are discussing here:
+
It is [[essentially]] saying that the formally [[ordained]] [[monastic]] [[sangha]] has a monopoly on living [[arhats]]. Why would this be important? To answer this we might look at a certain early [[Buddhist text]] in {{Wiki|Chinese}}, perhaps translated in the third or fourth century which, like the [[Dhammapada]], contains short quotes from various [[sūtras]]. It is called the [[Sūtra]] in Forty-Two [[Sections]]. The following line is relevant to what we are discussing here:
  
 
: 《四十二章經》卷1:「佛言:「飯凡人百不如飯一善人,飯善人千不如飯持五戒者一人,飯持五戒者萬人不如飯一須陀洹,飯須陀洹百萬不如飯一斯陀含,飯斯陀含千萬不如飯一阿那含,飯阿那含一億不如飯一阿羅漢」(CBETA, T17, no. 784, p. 722, c1-5)
 
: 《四十二章經》卷1:「佛言:「飯凡人百不如飯一善人,飯善人千不如飯持五戒者一人,飯持五戒者萬人不如飯一須陀洹,飯須陀洹百萬不如飯一斯陀含,飯斯陀含千萬不如飯一阿那含,飯阿那含一億不如飯一阿羅漢」(CBETA, T17, no. 784, p. 722, c1-5)
  
: The Buddha said, “To feed a hundred ordinary people is not as good as feeding one virtuous person. To feed one-thousand virtuous people is not as good as feeding one person who maintains the five precepts. To feed ten-thousand people who maintain the five precepts is not as good as feeding one stream-entrant. To feed one-million stream-entrants is not as good as feeding one once-returner. To feed ten-million once-returners is not as good as feeding one non-returner. To feed one-hundred million non-returners is not as good as feeding one arhat. …”
+
: The [[Buddha]] said, “To feed a hundred [[ordinary people]] is not as good as feeding one [[virtuous]] [[person]]. To feed one-thousand [[virtuous]] [[people]] is not as good as feeding one [[person]] who maintains the [[five precepts]]. To feed ten-thousand [[people]] who maintain the [[five precepts]] is not as good as feeding one stream-entrant. To feed one-million stream-entrants is not as good as feeding one [[once-returner]]. To feed ten-million [[once-returners]] is not as good as feeding one [[non-returner]]. To feed one-hundred million [[non-returners]] is not as good as feeding one [[arhat]]. …”
  
The idea that non-bhikṣus cannot achieve arhatship and live to tell about it is basically an attempt at disenfranchising and undermining the spiritual authority of non-monastic or unorthodox śramaṇas and lay practitioners. If we accept this belief, then any unofficial monk or yogi claiming to be an arhat past a day is either mistaken or lying. The formally ordained and institutional monastic sangha thereupon comes to have a monopoly over spiritual authority as they and they alone have arhats which are, next to rather rare pratyekabuddhas and buddhas, the ultimate field of merit for offerings. In other words, they are the wealthiest beings in terms of spiritual capital, and only the official sangha has them. This is effectively a consolidation and forced appropriation of spiritual capital.
+
The [[idea]] that non-bhikṣus cannot achieve [[arhatship]] and live to tell about it is basically an attempt at disenfranchising and undermining the [[spiritual]] authority of [[non-monastic]] or unorthodox [[śramaṇas]] and lay practitioners. If we accept this [[belief]], then any unofficial [[monk]] or [[yogi]] claiming to be an [[arhat]] {{Wiki|past}} a day is either mistaken or {{Wiki|lying}}. The formally [[ordained]] and institutional [[monastic]] [[sangha]] thereupon comes to have a monopoly over [[spiritual]] authority as they and they alone have [[arhats]] which are, next to rather rare [[pratyekabuddhas]] and [[buddhas]], the [[Wikipedia:Absolute (philosophy)|ultimate]] [[field of merit]] for [[offerings]]. In other words, they are the wealthiest [[beings]] in terms of [[spiritual]] capital, and only the official [[sangha]] has them. This is effectively a consolidation and forced appropriation of [[spiritual]] capital.
  
However, it goes a bit further than this. Indirectly another source of spiritual authority is gained through claiming to be the sole institute capable of realistically producing and actually retaining arhats past a day.
+
However, it goes a bit further than this. Indirectly another source of [[spiritual]] authority is gained through claiming to be the sole institute capable of realistically producing and actually retaining [[arhats]] {{Wiki|past}} a day.
  
As per the Vinaya regulations it is the fully ordained sangha which get to decide who will and will not be permitted to receive the full precepts. According to the ancient Vinaya literature they have a responsibility to weed out unsuitable ordinands based on various criteria (for instance, intersexual persons, debtors, those who have killed their parents, etc.). Receiving the full precepts is what legally makes you a field of merit, i.e., a receptacle for offerings producing boundless merit. In other words, you are invested with spiritual capital. Based on the logical conclusion from such ideas, the formal sangha has the power to decide who can and cannot achieve full liberation and not immediately drop dead thereafter.
+
As per the [[Vinaya]] regulations it is the fully [[ordained]] [[sangha]] which get to decide who will and will not be permitted to receive the full [[precepts]]. According to the {{Wiki|ancient}} [[Vinaya]] {{Wiki|literature}} they have a {{Wiki|responsibility}} to weed out unsuitable ordinands based on various criteria (for instance, intersexual persons, debtors, those who have killed their [[parents]], etc.). Receiving the full [[precepts]] is what legally makes you a [[field of merit]], i.e., a receptacle for [[offerings]] producing [[boundless]] [[merit]]. In other words, you are invested with [[spiritual]] capital. Based on the [[logical]] conclusion from such [[ideas]], the formal [[sangha]] has the power to decide who can and cannot achieve full [[liberation]] and not immediately drop [[dead]] thereafter.
  
Essentially, if a formal ordination is a prerequisite for arhatship, it is they and they alone who grant people the bliss of liberation. They put themselves in a position where they exercise supreme spiritual authority. It is like the old Church deciding who gets to go to heaven. If you should anger them, then you would not be buried properly and fall into hell. If they did not care for you, they could excommunicate you and this entailed hell. They subverted what was a personal spiritual quest into a very human operation and profited nicely from such arrangements as the vast wealth of Christian institutions past and present demonstrate.
+
[[Essentially]], if a formal [[ordination]] is a prerequisite for [[arhatship]], it is they and they alone who grant [[people]] the [[bliss]] of [[liberation]]. They put themselves in a position where they exercise supreme [[spiritual]] authority. It is like the old {{Wiki|Church}} deciding who gets to go to [[heaven]]. If you should [[anger]] them, then you would not be [[Wikipedia:burial|buried]] properly and fall into [[hell]]. If they did not care for you, they could excommunicate you and this entailed [[hell]]. They subverted what was a personal [[spiritual]] quest into a very [[human]] operation and profited nicely from such arrangements as the vast [[wealth]] of {{Wiki|Christian}} {{Wiki|institutions}} {{Wiki|past}} and {{Wiki|present}} demonstrate.
  
The same thing happened with some elements in Buddhism early on as well it seems. They subjugated the popular practice of supporting monks into a doctrinally justified spiritual monopoly. To question this might be regarded as slandering the third of the tri-ratna, which would entail suffering some ghoulish karmic punishments in hell as a result.
+
The same thing happened with some [[elements]] in [[Buddhism]] early on as well it seems. They subjugated the popular practice of supporting [[monks]] into a doctrinally justified [[spiritual]] monopoly. To question this might be regarded as slandering the third of the [[tri-ratna]], which would entail [[suffering]] some ghoulish [[karmic]] punishments in [[hell]] as a result.
  
We might wonder if this development was motivated by sinister purposes. I do not think this was the case. It seems to me, judging from the available history, that this development likely represents, generally speaking, the early division between forest dwelling monks (āraṇyaka) and urban dwelling monastics. The move towards monasticism was effectively motivated by changing social and religious environments which rendered the old models dangerously obsolete and required institutionalization of the sangha and Buddhadharma as a strategy for survival.
+
We might wonder if this [[development]] was motivated by sinister purposes. I do not think this was the case. It seems to me, judging from the available history, that this [[development]] likely represents, generally {{Wiki|speaking}}, the early [[division]] between {{Wiki|forest}} dwelling [[monks]] ([[āraṇyaka]]) and urban dwelling [[monastics]]. The move towards [[monasticism]] was effectively motivated by changing {{Wiki|social}} and [[religious]] environments which rendered the old models dangerously obsolete and required institutionalization of the [[sangha]] and [[Buddhadharma]] as a strategy for survival.
  
Bronkhorst's theory is that monastic Buddhism (i.e., the vihāra system) was a later development, perhaps appearing around the last century of the BCE era. One curious piece of evidence in support of this theory goes back to Aśoka (304-232 BCE) and his pillars. The specimen in question from 249 BCE is still found today at Lumbini in modern Nepal. Venerable Dhammika provides the following translation (see here):
+
Bronkhorst's {{Wiki|theory}} is that [[monastic]] [[Buddhism]] (i.e., the [[vihāra]] system) was a later [[development]], perhaps appearing around the last century of the BCE {{Wiki|era}}. One curious piece of {{Wiki|evidence}} in support of this {{Wiki|theory}} goes back to [[Aśoka]] (304-232 BCE) and his pillars. The specimen in question from 249 BCE is still found today at [[Lumbini]] in {{Wiki|modern}} [[Nepal]]. [[Venerable]] [[Dhammika]] provides the following translation (see here):
  
: Twenty years after his coronation, Beloved-of-the-Gods, King Piyadasi, visited this place and worshipped because here the Buddha, the sage of the Sakyans, was born. He had a stone figure and a pillar set up and because the Lord was born here, the village of Lumbini was exempted from tax and required to pay only one eighth of the produce.
+
: Twenty years after his {{Wiki|coronation}}, Beloved-of-the-Gods, [[King]] Piyadasi, visited this place and worshipped because here the [[Buddha]], the [[Wikipedia:Sage (sophos|sage]] of the [[Sakyans]], was born. He had a stone figure and a pillar set up and because the [[Lord]] was born here, the village of [[Lumbini]] was exempted from tax and required to pay only one eighth of the produce.
  
As Bronkhorst points out, what is interesting here is not what is said, but what is not said. There is no mention of a vihāra or giving the village to anyone. The villagers themselves are exempt from tax. Where are the monks and their monastery?<ref>{{Nolinking|Johannes Bronkhorst, Buddhism in the Shadow of Brahmanism Handbook of Oriental Studies (Leiden: Brill, 2011), 17-18.}}</ref>
+
As Bronkhorst points out, what is [[interesting]] here is not what is said, but what is not said. There is no mention of a [[vihāra]] or giving the village to anyone. The villagers themselves are exempt from tax. Where are the [[monks]] and their [[monastery]]?<ref>{{Nolinking|Johannes Bronkhorst, Buddhism in the Shadow of Brahmanism Handbook of Oriental Studies (Leiden: Brill, 2011), 17-18.}}</ref>
  
Unfortunately, the evidence needed to determine when this transition from mendicancy to monasticism occurred is still insufficient. Bronkhorst states,
+
Unfortunately, the {{Wiki|evidence}} needed to determine when this transition from mendicancy to [[monasticism]] occurred is still insufficient. Bronkhorst states,
  
: The historical evidence does not allow us to determine with precision when buddhist monks and nuns settled down permanently in monasteries. The first epigraphic evidence for the donation of land to monastic establishments in continental India may date from the first century ce. In Sri Lanka land grants were presumably already given to buddhist monasteries in the latter part of the second century bce, which may not be an unlikely date even for continental India. But whatever its exact date, when this important transition took place, Buddhism became more than ever before dependent upon rich and powerful donors. This in its turn involved it inextricably in political and social issues.<ref>{{Nolinking|Ibid., 19.}}</ref>
+
: The historical {{Wiki|evidence}} does not allow us to determine with precision when [[buddhist]] [[monks and nuns]] settled down permanently in [[monasteries]]. The first epigraphic {{Wiki|evidence}} for the donation of land to [[monastic]] establishments in continental [[India]] may date from the first century ce. In [[Sri Lanka]] land grants were presumably already given to [[buddhist]] [[monasteries]] in the latter part of the second century bce, which may not be an unlikely date even for continental [[India]]. But whatever its exact date, when this important transition took place, [[Buddhism]] became more than ever before [[dependent upon]] rich and powerful donors. This in its turn involved it inextricably in {{Wiki|political}} and {{Wiki|social}} issues.<ref>{{Nolinking|Ibid., 19.}}</ref>
  
In my opinion the move towards urban monastic arrangements was probably motivated by pragmatic concerns. The old lifestyle of mendicancy and homelessness was likely becoming problematic as time went on given increasing influences from Brahmanism and the hostility it displayed towards śramaṇa culture.
+
In my opinion the move towards urban [[monastic]] arrangements was probably motivated by {{Wiki|pragmatic}} concerns. The old lifestyle of mendicancy and homelessness was likely becoming problematic as [[time]] went on given increasing [[influences]] from [[Brahmanism]] and the {{Wiki|hostility}} it displayed towards [[śramaṇa]] {{Wiki|culture}}.
  
We need only consider the Śuṇga state (185-75 BCE) which was established by Puṣyamitra Śuṇga (185-149 BCE) following the end of the pro-Buddhist Maurya regime (322 BCE-185 BCE). While Puṣyamitra's activities are still debated by scholars, Giovanni Verardi in his work Hardships and Downfall of Buddhism provides a compelling case demonstrating that Puṣyamitra did in fact oppress Buddhism as part of his attempts to consolidate his power base and social arrangements which were in favor of Vedic orthodoxy.
+
We need only consider the Śuṇga state (185-75 BCE) which was established by Puṣyamitra Śuṇga (185-149 BCE) following the end of the pro-Buddhist {{Wiki|Maurya}} regime (322 BCE-185 BCE). While Puṣyamitra's [[activities]] are still [[debated]] by [[scholars]], Giovanni Verardi in his work {{Wiki|Hardships}} and Downfall of [[Buddhism]] provides a compelling case demonstrating that Puṣyamitra did in fact oppress [[Buddhism]] as part of his attempts to consolidate his power base and {{Wiki|social}} arrangements which were in favor of {{Wiki|Vedic}} {{Wiki|orthodoxy}}.
  
Virardi as evidence points to the fact that “there is a complete halt in the patronage of Buddhist monuments between Puṣyamitra's coup [185 BCE] and c. 100 BC. A second halt is observable between 75 BC and the early first century AD, after that Devabhūti's minister Vāsudeva, a brāhmaṇa, murdered the Śuṇga king in c. 73 BC, starting the orthodox Kāṇva rule. During the first halt, there is no trace of Buddhist monuments having been built anywhere in the Śuṇga territories.”<ref>{{Nolinking|Giovanni Veraridi, Hardships and Downfall of Buddhism in India (New Delhi, India: Manohar, 2011), 98.}}</ref>
+
Virardi [[as evidence]] points to the fact that “there is a complete halt in the {{Wiki|patronage}} of [[Buddhist]] monuments between Puṣyamitra's coup [185 BCE] and c. 100 BC. A second halt is observable between 75 BC and the early first century AD, after that Devabhūti's [[minister]] [[Vāsudeva]], a [[brāhmaṇa]], murdered the Śuṇga [[king]] in c. 73 BC, starting the {{Wiki|orthodox}} Kāṇva rule. During the first halt, there is no trace of [[Buddhist]] monuments having been built anywhere in the Śuṇga territories.”<ref>{{Nolinking|Giovanni Veraridi, Hardships and Downfall of Buddhism in India (New Delhi, India: Manohar, 2011), 98.}}</ref>
  
The greater religious environment under brahmanical influence was increasingly hostile towards śramaṇa culture. The Manusmṛti equates heretics (such as the Buddhists) to gamblers, bootleggers and so forth in that they must be expelled from the city as they oppress the king's subjects.<ref>{{Nolinking|Ibid., 149-150.}}</ref> It was in such a context that Buddhist traditions had to move out of forest, so to speak, towards landed monasticism. One might think the forest was a safer option in some regions, and presumably such traditions carried on as evidence would suggest, but the vulnerability of disorganized and decentralized śramaṇa communities would have been apparent to the Buddhists living under and immediately after Śuṇga rule. Having a consolidated institution with influential benefactors would have been a safer option than being a community of largely decentralized semi-democratic mendicants.
+
The greater [[religious]] environment under [[brahmanical]] influence was increasingly {{Wiki|hostile}} towards [[śramaṇa]] {{Wiki|culture}}. The {{Wiki|Manusmṛti}} equates {{Wiki|heretics}} (such as the [[Buddhists]]) to gamblers, bootleggers and so forth in that they must be expelled from the city as they oppress the king's [[subjects]].<ref>{{Nolinking|Ibid., 149-150.}}</ref> It was in such a context that [[Buddhist traditions]] had to move out of {{Wiki|forest}}, so to speak, towards landed [[monasticism]]. One might think the {{Wiki|forest}} was a safer option in some regions, and presumably such [[traditions]] carried on [[as evidence]] would suggest, but the vulnerability of disorganized and decentralized [[śramaṇa]] communities would have been apparent to the [[Buddhists]] living under and immediately after Śuṇga rule. Having a consolidated institution with influential benefactors would have been a safer option than being a {{Wiki|community}} of largely decentralized semi-democratic {{Wiki|mendicants}}.
  
The development of a strict Vinaya system and organized sangha with formal ordination procedures was probably a slow process (or rather, a slow accumulation of economic, spiritual, cultural and social capitals). Even by the time the Mahāyāna emerges it was still not entirely consolidated and legitimate. In an earlier post [[Flexible Mahāyāna Ethics]] we took a look at how the Vimalakīrti Sūtra, an early Mahāyāna sūtra, actually mocks the Vinaya system when Śāriputra is portrayed as concerned about being showered by a goddess in flowers he cannot remove. His concern is with the letter of the law: monks cannot be adorned with flowers. If the Vinaya is late period literature, then quite possibly when the Vimalakīrti Sūtra appeared the Vinaya system was still developing and hence not universally accepted as canonical. If the early Mahāyāna proponents had seen it as canonical (buddhavacana or the words of the Buddha), then presumably they might not have made such a mockery of it.
+
The [[development]] of a strict [[Vinaya]] system and organized [[sangha]] with formal [[ordination]] procedures was probably a slow process (or rather, a slow [[accumulation]] of economic, [[spiritual]], {{Wiki|cultural}} and {{Wiki|social}} capitals). Even by the [[time]] the [[Mahāyāna]] emerges it was still not entirely consolidated and legitimate. In an earlier post [[Flexible Mahāyāna Ethics]] we took a look at how the [[Vimalakīrti Sūtra]], an early [[Mahāyāna sūtra]], actually mocks the [[Vinaya]] system when [[Śāriputra]] is portrayed as concerned about being showered by a [[goddess]] in [[flowers]] he cannot remove. His [[concern]] is with the [[letter]] of the law: [[monks]] cannot be [[adorned with flowers]]. If the [[Vinaya]] is late period {{Wiki|literature}}, then quite possibly when the [[Vimalakīrti Sūtra]] appeared the [[Vinaya]] system was still developing and hence not universally accepted as [[Wikipedia:canonical|canonical]]. If the early [[Mahāyāna]] proponents had seen it as [[Wikipedia:canonical|canonical]] ([[buddhavacana]] or the words of the [[Buddha]]), then presumably they might not have made such a mockery of it.
  
Nevertheless, the power consolidation of the Vinaya was never absolute in India. The fact of the matter is that a lay priesthood developed early on, much to the dismay of Vinaya proponents. In a future post we will have to take a look at how such a non-monastic Buddhist priesthood existed in ancient India plus later developments on the subcontinent and elsewhere.
+
Nevertheless, the power consolidation of the [[Vinaya]] was never [[absolute]] in [[India]]. The fact of the {{Wiki|matter}} is that a lay priesthood developed early on, much to the dismay of [[Vinaya]] proponents. In a {{Wiki|future}} post we will have to take a look at how such a [[non-monastic]] [[Buddhist]] priesthood existed in {{Wiki|ancient India}} plus later developments on the subcontinent and elsewhere.
  
At this point we might wonder where Buddhism(s) can go from here. As outlined above a lot of the original democratic ideas as the Buddha proposed them were either ignored or rendered obsolete. In foreign lands they were simply alien and consequently not implemented. However, in a modern liberal democratic country with universal suffrage, the cultural environment within which democratic principles are appreciated and respected might lend itself to more egalitarian power structures. Spiritual leadership could be decided by the vote of all members, senior and junior, rather than appointment. This already happens in many places, but then at the same time foreign power structures are either reproduced or affirmed in lands where Buddhism is still in its infancy, thus undermining any movement towards real equality (this assumes enough people want equality).
+
At this point we might wonder where Buddhism(s) can go from here. As outlined above a lot of the original democratic [[ideas]] as the [[Buddha]] proposed them were either ignored or rendered obsolete. In foreign lands they were simply alien and consequently not implemented. However, in a {{Wiki|modern}} liberal democratic country with [[universal]] suffrage, the {{Wiki|cultural}} environment within which democratic {{Wiki|principles}} are appreciated and respected might lend itself to more {{Wiki|egalitarian}} power structures. [[Spiritual]] [[leadership]] could be decided by the vote of all members, senior and junior, rather than appointment. This already happens in many places, but then at the same [[time]] foreign power structures are either reproduced or [[affirmed]] in lands where [[Buddhism]] is still in its infancy, thus undermining any {{Wiki|movement}} towards real equality (this assumes enough [[people]] want equality).
  
We do not have to have appointed titles, strict hierarchies and gender inequalities in our organizations, and all things considered we might as well be better off without them if our cultural background is essentially in favour of equality. In other words what works in one culture will not necessarily be optimal in another.
+
We do not have to have appointed titles, strict hierarchies and [[gender]] inequalities in our organizations, and all things considered we might as well be better off without them if our {{Wiki|cultural}} background is [[essentially]] in favour of equality. In other words what works in one {{Wiki|culture}} will not necessarily be optimal in another.
  
This might be an ideal, but nevertheless it could be implemented. One obstacle of course is beliefs that depend on institutional authority. One example of this is the idea of "Dharma transmission" which is an undemocratic transfer of spiritual and sometimes institutional authority from master to disciple in Zen and Chan. If the community really believes this somehow entitles the appointed leader to special privileges, exemptions and teaching rights, then egalitarian ideals will just remain ideals.
+
This might be an {{Wiki|ideal}}, but nevertheless it could be implemented. One [[obstacle]] of course is [[beliefs]] that depend on institutional authority. One example of this is the [[idea]] of "[[Dharma transmission]]" which is an undemocratic transfer of [[spiritual]] and sometimes institutional authority from [[master]] to [[disciple]] in [[Zen]] and [[Chan]]. If the {{Wiki|community}} really believes this somehow entitles the appointed leader to special privileges, exemptions and [[teaching]] rights, then {{Wiki|egalitarian}} ideals will just remain ideals.
  
One alternative would be to simply go back to the Buddha's original intent: be an island onto yourself and place spiritual authority into the abstract Dharma rather than individuals, in which case the right to teach and the respect that comes with being a guide would be determined based on one's knowledge and implementation of the Dharma rather than some kind of institutionalized sanctioning and/or title.
+
One alternative would be to simply go back to the [[Buddha's]] original intent: be an island onto yourself and place [[spiritual]] authority into the abstract [[Dharma]] rather than {{Wiki|individuals}}, in which case the right to teach and the [[respect]] that comes with being a [[guide]] would be determined based on one's [[knowledge]] and implementation of the [[Dharma]] rather than some kind of institutionalized sanctioning and/or title.
  
 
{{reflist}}
 
{{reflist}}

Revision as of 12:13, 15 July 2014

Budghhtery.jpg
Ksitigarbha-es28.jpg
BbynvnMJ8.jpg
Krishna .jpg
2775.jpg
Enhaxc03-7.jpg
56529- rge.jpg
Arahath mahinda.jpg
Fifth Dalai.JPG
Vaishravana-Vajrapani.jpg
Bb1c4f84637.jpg
Au.JPG

Power and Inequality in Buddhism
By Indrajala (Jeffrey Kotyk)



The nature of power and authority within Buddhism is a potentially volatile subject, especially for many modern day people who advocate equality and egalitarianism. Such ideals are no doubt heavily influenced by modern movements towards democracy and such recent ideologies as feminism which seeks to correct perceived inequalities and injustices. Buddhism in popular culture is normally perceived as being egalitarian and quite compatible with liberal western democratic values. Not only is it a religion of tolerance, but one that promotes equality.

Such prescriptive ideals are at odds with the historical and present realities. Historically long ago hierarchy and inequality became essentially hard wired into the institutional religion(s) we call Buddhism(s), and we will look at this in this post. This might be disagreeable to contemporary western sensibilities, but until recently, and perhaps even still, a prescribed hierarchy and vast degree of inequality between Buddhists would not have registered as problematic for most Asian cultures.

The Buddha is on record as having told his disciples two pertinent things in respect to how the tradition he founded was to be developed and practised. It needs firstly to be noted that he never appointed a successor, though figures like Mahākāśyapa did take a lead role in formulating the canon according to the traditional histories. He also insisted that practitioners be “islands onto themselves”. This is significant because it illustrates that a strict hierarchy based on spiritual authority and autocratic control of a community was not the Buddha's intent. As the founder of the sangha he had a degree of charismatic authority no doubt, but he did in fact establish a democratic mechanism within the sangha for deciding on matters through tacit consent of the whole assembly.

Let us consider two relevant quotes as follows.

Therefore, Ananda, be islands unto yourselves, refuges unto yourselves, seeking no external refuge; with the Dhamma as your island, the Dhamma as your refuge, seeking no other refuge. (DN 16)

Here is the famous statement where the Buddha instructs us to rely on ourselves with the Dharma/Dhamma as our refuge. He does not instruct Ānanda to rely on lineage or authority. We also have the Buddha explicitly stating he will appoint no successor.

“Is there, Master Ananda, any single bhikkhu who was appointed by Master Gotama thus: ‘He will be your refuge when I am gone,’ and whom you now have recourse to?”
“There is no single bhikkhu, brahmin, who was appointed by the Blessed One who knows and sees, accomplished and fully enlightened, thus: ‘He will be your refuge when I am gone,’ and whom we now have recourse to.”
“But is there, Master Ananda, any single bhikkhu who has been chosen by the Sangha and appointed by a number of elder bhikkhus thus: ‘He will be our refuge after the Blessed One has gone,’ and whom you now have recourse to?”
“There is no single bhikkhu, brahmin, who has been chosen by the Sangha and appointed by a number of elder bhikkhus thus: ‘He will be our refuge after the Blessed One has gone,’ and whom we now have recourse to.”
“But if you have no refuge, Master Ananda, what is the cause for your concord?”
“We are not without a refuge, brahmin. We have a refuge; we have the Dhamma as our refuge.”
(MN 108)

According to this, the Buddha placed spiritual authority in the Dharma rather than a human successor or even the assembly of arhats which might have been a logical option. There is no mention of lineage blessings or some type of “Dharma transmission” which would bestow institutional authority on select individuals. It seems that, based on the early canon, there is no basis for lineages as they came to develop. Spiritual authority was first placed in the abstract Dharma. This would mean no person could claim special status or privileges based on title or appointment. A person was to be judged based on their cultivation of Dharma.

Nevertheless, as a community there were still means to adjudicate and make collective decisions. While the dating of the Vinaya literature is debated, I believe that at least some of it reflects historical fact or at least a somewhat later cultural memory of how things were established originally.

One example of this are the more or less democratic procedures with which formal decisions were made within the sangha such as ordinations, forced exiles and other such matters. The karma proceedings as they are called are carried out through tacit consent. Basically, a proposition would be put forward before the required minimum number of present bhikṣus and provided there were no objections and the assembly remained silent it would be passed. If any objections arose, then they had to be resolved before the motion was passed.

In light of all this, we might ask what basis there is for appointed titles and leadership roles that effectively function as autocracies, especially outside of India?

We need to consider the fact that as Buddhism spread to foreign lands, such as China, the original democratic principles enshrined in the Vinaya would have seemed quite alien to heavily hierarchical societies which determined authority based on one's ancestry. This naturally led to a reproduction of clan-like structures in the Buddhist communities where monastic disciples functioned as adopted sons.

In Chinese Buddhism from early on it seems that legitimacy was decided based on constructed lineage charts with sufficient aggrandized figures throughout the past, which was not at all unlike family tablets and the mechanism for legitimizing elite power. Having no formal leadership and deciding on things by vote would not have worked in such a culture. This perhaps also helps to explain why the karma proceedings as per the Vinaya were never really implemented throughout Chinese history despite the texts for it having been translated in the early fifth century.

However, the formation of hierarchy and lineage in Buddhism is rooted in other factors. The analysis here can go a lot deeper with recourse to general sociology. Human organizations tend towards individuals forming cliques and acquiring collective power for themselves. In a religious context spiritual authority is often just as potent as economic, social and cultural powers. Spiritual capital is also exchangeable for economic and political capitals as well, which furthers the aims of a given institution within a society. A religious institution will inevitably want state sanction plus a stable economic base with which to develop and expand its infrastructure and membership. This is in contrast to unorganized religious communities where power is dispersed and consequently complex projects, such as defensive strategies against hostile forces as the Buddhists required, prove difficult if not simply infeasible.

I should say something about Pierre Bourdieu's (1930-2002) model here. It is actually quite useful when analysing power structures within Buddhism. In his work The Forms of Capital (1986), he specifies three types of capital:

  • Economic capital: economic resources such as cash and assets.
  • Social capital: resources linked to a “durable network of more or less institutionalized relationships of mutual acquaintance and recognition”.
  • Cultural capital: knowledge, education and skills which elevates someone to a higher status in their society.

Bourdieu's theory was quite innovative in that he addressed the issue of inequality by looking at factors outside the immediate economic sphere. This is especially pertinent to Buddhism where inequality historically has and still exists. John Field explains Boudieu's concern with social hierarchy:

To understand Bourdieu's thinking on social capital, we need to remember that his main concern was and is the understanding of social hierarchy. In many ways, he was engaging with a body of ideas that was deeply influenced by Marxist sociology. He thought that 'economic capital is at the root of all other types of capital', and he was interested in the ways in which it could be combined with other forms of capital to create and reproduce inequality. For Bourdieu, inequality was to be explained by the production and reproduction of capital. He reminded that readers that captial 'is accumulated labor' which 'takes time to accumulate'. But to see capital solely in economic terms was insufficient. Certainly economic exchanges are geared towards profit, and are therefore pursued out of self-interest. Yet Bourdieu challenged the conventional view that immaterial exchanges - the universe of the artist, or that of love and marriage - were somehow to be respected as 'disinterested'. Both cultural capital and social capital should be treated as assets, representing the product of accumulated labour.[1]

I believe we can also add spiritual capital to the above list as a unique form of capital which promotes interests beyond economic means. It would of course be related to cultural and social capitals, but beyond that there is a sort of power that comes with widespread belief in some religious icon, person or idea that is convertible into other forms of capital and which fosters inequality within a given community.

In Buddhism these four types of capital are all present.

Spiritual capital would be the ability to command the labor and resources of a community based on people's religious beliefs. The lowly laywoman in the temple kitchen has no spiritual capital and thus would receive no offerings from the larger community. She would exercise minimal power in the decision making process. In traditional Buddhist thought her gender would be seen as a handicap to spiritual attainments and her lack of renunciate status would likewise diminish her chances of acquiring any spiritual capital. Meanwhile the celebrated renunciate arhat would possess vast stores of spiritual capital despite not having a dime to his (or her) name. This spiritual capital would be just as valuable as social or cultural capital as the faith in him as a "field of merit" and teacher of liberation could literally move mountains if he asked for a monastery to be built and sufficient numbers of people believed in him.

Cultural capital would be all the skills and knowledge necessary for priestcraft, religious theater, exegesis, chanting, scripture copying and related fields. One prime example of cultural capital in much of the Buddhist world is skill in calligraphy. Tibetan and East Asian monks can spend many years perfecting their art. Kūkai's work so admired that people to this day emulate his hand; both his Chinese characters and siddham script (Sanskrit). In premodern East Asia skill at calligraphy was a sign of good education, personal cultivation, patience and class, all of which distinguished the master from the common monastics. In modern days as well the fine works of eminent figures are prominently displayed for the public to admire and even emulate. Around many contemporary Taiwanese monasteries the works of their respective masters are positioned in key locations for people to readily view, such as in the dining or reception halls. The work of anyone else is only naturally not considered worthy enough. The master's work raised above all not only affirms his or her status, but indirectly diminishes the status of everyone else. As representatives of their organization their calligraphy can essentially function as subtle power projection where a sharp eye can admire their skill which would only naturally reflect their other good qualities such as leadership.

Social capital within Buddhism might be best illustrated by lineages or sects. Membership in a given lineage brings with it various privileges which might include immediate access to material resources, even simple things like free food and shelter which outsiders would be forced to pay for with labor or cash. The status that comes with having an elevated position within an organization further amplifies inequality. For instance, if you are a senior monk you probably will not be asked to sweep the floor and clean toilets, whereas the lowly novices are given such dirty jobs and in due time they pass such tasks on to their underlings. Those in elevated social positions within a Buddhist organization generally enjoy the fruits of others' labours, and all this is justifiable given their social status.

The official sangha is tied in with social capital as well. The sangha is a “field of merit”. This is a social construct where formally ordained monastics are given material offerings as a means of generating merit which is believed to result in good tidings in this and future lives. Their position is strictly demarcated from that of common laypeople. The laypeople cook the rice and give it to the monks and receive merit plus teachings. The sangha might request the laypeople construct something on their behalf (the classic example is a meditation hut) and given the accumulated capital of the sangha it probably gets done. Here we see the interplay between the different forms of capital. Cultural, social and spiritual capitals are easily converted to physical goods and services, as well as economic capital.

For many centuries the sangha has found itself in a kind of dual world where on one hand as renunciates having personal wealth was ostensibly taboo and contrary to the Vinaya, and on the other would accumulate vast amounts of assets and cash as a collective body. People and states would make offerings of land and money to the sangha in exchange for merit, teachings, social unification and regime legitimization (see my earlier post entitled Buddhism & Early States - Tibet and Japan ). In many cases throughout Buddhist history economic capital was essential in acquiring the other forms of capital. In order to become literate and able to compose decent verses in East Asia for example one needed paper, a set of the classics, a tutor and other such essentials, all of which cost money. A monastery could in theory provide such things, but again this possibly came with a financial cost in China which had a cash economy.

Even spiritual capital in some cases had to be acquired through exchanging economic capital. One prime example of this is the necessity to make expensive offerings in order to receive some tantric empowerments, though having such empowerments in some cultures elevated one's social status and ability to acquire further capital. Kūkai for instance was able to have several large monasteries built after returning from China because he could offer the aristocracy new and advanced forms of ritual technology from the continent which they saw great benefit in. He alone did not have sufficient economic capital to build such institutions, but his spiritual capital, which was gained through a trip to China paid for with gold, was eventually convertible to real life goods and services well beyond his economic means to acquire.

It is of course quite reasonable in some contexts to consciously attempt to gain a monopoly over spiritual authority because a dispersion of that authority would not only undermine the personal power base of religious elites needed for a linear direction, but also undermine the accumulated spiritual authority necessary for substantial projects which further the interests of both the common devotee and the ecclesiastical elites.

We can identify one early example of such an attempt at power acquisition in early Buddhist literature. For instance, according to the Milindapanha (the Questions of Milinda), in order to attain arhatship and live through it one must formally ordain as a bhikṣu/bhikkhu, otherwise as a layperson one will die within a day. Consider the following:

"If a layman attains arahant-ship, only two destinations await him; either he must enter the Order that very day or else he must attain parinibbàna"
Milindapanha III.19
"You say that if a layman attains arahantship he must either enter the Order that very day or die and attain parinibbàna. Yet if he is unable to find a robe and bowl and preceptor then that exalted condition of arahantship is a waste, for destruction of life is involved in it."
"The fault does not lie with arahantship but with the state of a layman, because it is too weak to support arahantship. Just as, O king, although food protects the life of beings it will take away the life of one whose digestion is weak; so too, if a layman attains arahantship he must, because of the weakness of that condition, enter the Order that very day or die."
Milindapanha III.62

We need to consider what this is really saying and who benefits from such a belief. As Cicero suggested: cui bono? Who benefits from this? Unless we accept the stated belief as is, we might wonder if there is not an alternative motive behind these ideas.

It is essentially saying that the formally ordained monastic sangha has a monopoly on living arhats. Why would this be important? To answer this we might look at a certain early Buddhist text in Chinese, perhaps translated in the third or fourth century which, like the Dhammapada, contains short quotes from various sūtras. It is called the Sūtra in Forty-Two Sections. The following line is relevant to what we are discussing here:

《四十二章經》卷1:「佛言:「飯凡人百不如飯一善人,飯善人千不如飯持五戒者一人,飯持五戒者萬人不如飯一須陀洹,飯須陀洹百萬不如飯一斯陀含,飯斯陀含千萬不如飯一阿那含,飯阿那含一億不如飯一阿羅漢」(CBETA, T17, no. 784, p. 722, c1-5)
The Buddha said, “To feed a hundred ordinary people is not as good as feeding one virtuous person. To feed one-thousand virtuous people is not as good as feeding one person who maintains the five precepts. To feed ten-thousand people who maintain the five precepts is not as good as feeding one stream-entrant. To feed one-million stream-entrants is not as good as feeding one once-returner. To feed ten-million once-returners is not as good as feeding one non-returner. To feed one-hundred million non-returners is not as good as feeding one arhat. …”

The idea that non-bhikṣus cannot achieve arhatship and live to tell about it is basically an attempt at disenfranchising and undermining the spiritual authority of non-monastic or unorthodox śramaṇas and lay practitioners. If we accept this belief, then any unofficial monk or yogi claiming to be an arhat past a day is either mistaken or lying. The formally ordained and institutional monastic sangha thereupon comes to have a monopoly over spiritual authority as they and they alone have arhats which are, next to rather rare pratyekabuddhas and buddhas, the ultimate field of merit for offerings. In other words, they are the wealthiest beings in terms of spiritual capital, and only the official sangha has them. This is effectively a consolidation and forced appropriation of spiritual capital.

However, it goes a bit further than this. Indirectly another source of spiritual authority is gained through claiming to be the sole institute capable of realistically producing and actually retaining arhats past a day.

As per the Vinaya regulations it is the fully ordained sangha which get to decide who will and will not be permitted to receive the full precepts. According to the ancient Vinaya literature they have a responsibility to weed out unsuitable ordinands based on various criteria (for instance, intersexual persons, debtors, those who have killed their parents, etc.). Receiving the full precepts is what legally makes you a field of merit, i.e., a receptacle for offerings producing boundless merit. In other words, you are invested with spiritual capital. Based on the logical conclusion from such ideas, the formal sangha has the power to decide who can and cannot achieve full liberation and not immediately drop dead thereafter.

Essentially, if a formal ordination is a prerequisite for arhatship, it is they and they alone who grant people the bliss of liberation. They put themselves in a position where they exercise supreme spiritual authority. It is like the old Church deciding who gets to go to heaven. If you should anger them, then you would not be buried properly and fall into hell. If they did not care for you, they could excommunicate you and this entailed hell. They subverted what was a personal spiritual quest into a very human operation and profited nicely from such arrangements as the vast wealth of Christian institutions past and present demonstrate.

The same thing happened with some elements in Buddhism early on as well it seems. They subjugated the popular practice of supporting monks into a doctrinally justified spiritual monopoly. To question this might be regarded as slandering the third of the tri-ratna, which would entail suffering some ghoulish karmic punishments in hell as a result.

We might wonder if this development was motivated by sinister purposes. I do not think this was the case. It seems to me, judging from the available history, that this development likely represents, generally speaking, the early division between forest dwelling monks (āraṇyaka) and urban dwelling monastics. The move towards monasticism was effectively motivated by changing social and religious environments which rendered the old models dangerously obsolete and required institutionalization of the sangha and Buddhadharma as a strategy for survival.

Bronkhorst's theory is that monastic Buddhism (i.e., the vihāra system) was a later development, perhaps appearing around the last century of the BCE era. One curious piece of evidence in support of this theory goes back to Aśoka (304-232 BCE) and his pillars. The specimen in question from 249 BCE is still found today at Lumbini in modern Nepal. Venerable Dhammika provides the following translation (see here):

Twenty years after his coronation, Beloved-of-the-Gods, King Piyadasi, visited this place and worshipped because here the Buddha, the sage of the Sakyans, was born. He had a stone figure and a pillar set up and because the Lord was born here, the village of Lumbini was exempted from tax and required to pay only one eighth of the produce.

As Bronkhorst points out, what is interesting here is not what is said, but what is not said. There is no mention of a vihāra or giving the village to anyone. The villagers themselves are exempt from tax. Where are the monks and their monastery?[2]

Unfortunately, the evidence needed to determine when this transition from mendicancy to monasticism occurred is still insufficient. Bronkhorst states,

The historical evidence does not allow us to determine with precision when buddhist monks and nuns settled down permanently in monasteries. The first epigraphic evidence for the donation of land to monastic establishments in continental India may date from the first century ce. In Sri Lanka land grants were presumably already given to buddhist monasteries in the latter part of the second century bce, which may not be an unlikely date even for continental India. But whatever its exact date, when this important transition took place, Buddhism became more than ever before dependent upon rich and powerful donors. This in its turn involved it inextricably in political and social issues.[3]

In my opinion the move towards urban monastic arrangements was probably motivated by pragmatic concerns. The old lifestyle of mendicancy and homelessness was likely becoming problematic as time went on given increasing influences from Brahmanism and the hostility it displayed towards śramaṇa culture.

We need only consider the Śuṇga state (185-75 BCE) which was established by Puṣyamitra Śuṇga (185-149 BCE) following the end of the pro-Buddhist Maurya regime (322 BCE-185 BCE). While Puṣyamitra's activities are still debated by scholars, Giovanni Verardi in his work Hardships and Downfall of Buddhism provides a compelling case demonstrating that Puṣyamitra did in fact oppress Buddhism as part of his attempts to consolidate his power base and social arrangements which were in favor of Vedic orthodoxy.

Virardi as evidence points to the fact that “there is a complete halt in the patronage of Buddhist monuments between Puṣyamitra's coup [185 BCE] and c. 100 BC. A second halt is observable between 75 BC and the early first century AD, after that Devabhūti's minister Vāsudeva, a brāhmaṇa, murdered the Śuṇga king in c. 73 BC, starting the orthodox Kāṇva rule. During the first halt, there is no trace of Buddhist monuments having been built anywhere in the Śuṇga territories.”[4]

The greater religious environment under brahmanical influence was increasingly hostile towards śramaṇa culture. The Manusmṛti equates heretics (such as the Buddhists) to gamblers, bootleggers and so forth in that they must be expelled from the city as they oppress the king's subjects.[5] It was in such a context that Buddhist traditions had to move out of forest, so to speak, towards landed monasticism. One might think the forest was a safer option in some regions, and presumably such traditions carried on as evidence would suggest, but the vulnerability of disorganized and decentralized śramaṇa communities would have been apparent to the Buddhists living under and immediately after Śuṇga rule. Having a consolidated institution with influential benefactors would have been a safer option than being a community of largely decentralized semi-democratic mendicants.

The development of a strict Vinaya system and organized sangha with formal ordination procedures was probably a slow process (or rather, a slow accumulation of economic, spiritual, cultural and social capitals). Even by the time the Mahāyāna emerges it was still not entirely consolidated and legitimate. In an earlier post Flexible Mahāyāna Ethics we took a look at how the Vimalakīrti Sūtra, an early Mahāyāna sūtra, actually mocks the Vinaya system when Śāriputra is portrayed as concerned about being showered by a goddess in flowers he cannot remove. His concern is with the letter of the law: monks cannot be adorned with flowers. If the Vinaya is late period literature, then quite possibly when the Vimalakīrti Sūtra appeared the Vinaya system was still developing and hence not universally accepted as canonical. If the early Mahāyāna proponents had seen it as canonical (buddhavacana or the words of the Buddha), then presumably they might not have made such a mockery of it.

Nevertheless, the power consolidation of the Vinaya was never absolute in India. The fact of the matter is that a lay priesthood developed early on, much to the dismay of Vinaya proponents. In a future post we will have to take a look at how such a non-monastic Buddhist priesthood existed in ancient India plus later developments on the subcontinent and elsewhere.

At this point we might wonder where Buddhism(s) can go from here. As outlined above a lot of the original democratic ideas as the Buddha proposed them were either ignored or rendered obsolete. In foreign lands they were simply alien and consequently not implemented. However, in a modern liberal democratic country with universal suffrage, the cultural environment within which democratic principles are appreciated and respected might lend itself to more egalitarian power structures. Spiritual leadership could be decided by the vote of all members, senior and junior, rather than appointment. This already happens in many places, but then at the same time foreign power structures are either reproduced or affirmed in lands where Buddhism is still in its infancy, thus undermining any movement towards real equality (this assumes enough people want equality).

We do not have to have appointed titles, strict hierarchies and gender inequalities in our organizations, and all things considered we might as well be better off without them if our cultural background is essentially in favour of equality. In other words what works in one culture will not necessarily be optimal in another.

This might be an ideal, but nevertheless it could be implemented. One obstacle of course is beliefs that depend on institutional authority. One example of this is the idea of "Dharma transmission" which is an undemocratic transfer of spiritual and sometimes institutional authority from master to disciple in Zen and Chan. If the community really believes this somehow entitles the appointed leader to special privileges, exemptions and teaching rights, then egalitarian ideals will just remain ideals.

One alternative would be to simply go back to the Buddha's original intent: be an island onto yourself and place spiritual authority into the abstract Dharma rather than individuals, in which case the right to teach and the respect that comes with being a guide would be determined based on one's knowledge and implementation of the Dharma rather than some kind of institutionalized sanctioning and/or title.

Footnotes

  1. John Field, Social Capital, Second Edition (Routledge, 2009), 18.
  2. Johannes Bronkhorst, Buddhism in the Shadow of Brahmanism Handbook of Oriental Studies (Leiden: Brill, 2011), 17-18.
  3. Ibid., 19.
  4. Giovanni Veraridi, Hardships and Downfall of Buddhism in India (New Delhi, India: Manohar, 2011), 98.
  5. Ibid., 149-150.

Source

by Indrajala (Jeffrey Kotyk)
huayanzang.blogspot.com.au